After coming to power in the late 17th century, Peter the Great of Russia decided to escape the confines of the Kremlin and travel incognito across Europe for a variety of diplomatic and personal reasons.
During his European odyssey, Peter visited Holland and was amazed at the commercial success of the small nation. In a fantastic biography of the young tsar, Robert Massie writes how “Peter could not escape asking himself how it was that his own people…produced only enough to feed themselves, whereas here in Amsterdam…more convertible wealth had been accumulated than in all the expanse of Russia.”
Get Evonomics in your inbox
Trade was clearly a factor, but so too was religious toleration. Holland at the time was what Mathis calls an “intellectual and artistic clearinghouse” where clever thinkers, who let their pen or mouth wander too far, escaped repressive regimes. In this land of inquisitive minds, Dutch religious tolerance was born. While this principle was not encoded in law, people would “look the other way” so that Calvinists, Catholics, and others could live together peacefully and productively.
Peter began to realize that Dutch commercial prosperity largely derived from its tolerant nature. He left Europe “intrigued by the atmosphere of religious toleration” and swore to mitigate the intolerance and rigidity of the Russian Orthodox Church on his return home.
As Peter was discovering the benefits of an inclusive society, the English philosopher John Locke published A Letter Concerning Toleration a few years after fleeing to Holland himself. Inspired by his time in the Dutch Republic, Locke argued that religious tolerance was the best way to structure a society. Radically, he advocated for “toleration not only for the ‘different professions of religion’ within Christianity but for all religions.”
While that may not strike the modern reader as particularly controversial, in the late 17th century, religious institutions and states displayed little regard for those who did not conform to the predominant belief system. The Catholic Church summed up this sentiment best with their antagonizing phrase: “Outside the Church there is no salvation.”
Locke’s Letter, while focused on religious tolerance, was ultimately about creating a more inclusive society. That civilizational struggle still continues to this day in the Western world, but this time the exclusive force comes not from religion, but from economics.
The levels of wealth inequality across the world and in nations is, to put it lightly, suboptimally distributed. The United States offers a sterling example. Brookings senior fellow, Richard Reeves, looked at Congressional Budget Office data and found the top 20 percent “saw a $4 trillion increase in pretax income in the years between 1979 and 2013” while “the combined rise for the bottom 80 percent…was just over $3 trillion.”
The only way to defend wealth distortion like this is to claim a well-functioning society necessitates great inequality. Just like the religious intolerance of yore, today’s exclusive brand of economics is clearly not the best way to organize a group of people, but instead represents the best way for a few individuals to maintain power and wealth.
The myth of exclusivity’s benefits must be erased once again, because our current economic philosophy is holding back our human potential. A system like this is not how you engender the most creativity or productivity in a people. Rather, it is how you fertilize frustration and disenchantment, which we’ve seen manifest recently in the election of Donald Trump and Brexit. This call to action should not be mistaken as a call to true egalitarianism, it is a recognition that too few people possess too much of the capital today.
It’s not that the today’s economy is doing everything wrong. On the contrary, extreme poverty has been greatly reduced, advances in medicine have flourished, and an unimaginable array of goods and services have been unleashed. Yet like the Catholic Church, which spurred philosophical breakthroughs, cathedrals, and pieces of art, these wonderful achievements do not shield these exclusive forces from critique.
Why Nations Fail, a terrific book on the history of civilizations, spends many chapters illustrating why “inclusive economic and political institutions do not emerge by themselves.” History has shown us that exclusive institutions do not abdicate power unless they are forced to. Inclusive societies often come about “from significant conflict between elites resisting economic growth and political change and those wishing to limit the economic and political power of existing elites.”
Thought of in this way, the rampant inequality and exclusionary economics of today’s Western economies are merely another “significant conflict” between those resisting inclusivity and those benefitting from the system. Just as Peter the Great realized exclusionary forces suppress prosperity, we need to see through the lies which hold up the current economic system. For as Locke wrote, “it seems monstrous for men to be so blind as not to perceive the necessity and advantage” of a more inclusive world.
Originally published at Civic Skunk Works.
2017 August 10
Donating = Changing Economics. And Changing the World.
Evonomics is free, it’s a labor of love, and it's an expense. We spend hundreds of hours and lots of dollars each month creating, curating, and promoting content that drives the next evolution of economics. If you're like us — if you think there’s a key leverage point here for making the world a better place — please consider donating. We’ll use your donation to deliver even more game-changing content, and to spread the word about that content to influential thinkers far and wide.
MONTHLY DONATION
$3 / month
$7 / month
$10 / month
$25 / month
You can also become a one-time patron with a single donation in any amount.
If you liked this article, you'll also like these other Evonomics articles...
BE INVOLVED
We welcome you to take part in the next evolution of economics. Sign up now to be kept in the loop!