Economics

We’re All Free Riders. Get over It!

Public goods of the twenty-first century

Share with your friends










Submit
More share buttons
Share on Pinterest

By Nicholas Gruen

The free rider problem

Anathematized and stigmatized today, free-riders built the lion’s share of the prosperity we enjoy today. Does that mean we should ‘share’ or ‘pirate’ more copyrighted things on the internet? Not necessarily. The free rider problem is real enough. If it costs vast sums to test a new drug, we can’t expect the market to do so if all that investment can be undercut by imitators.

But here’s the thing. In addition to the free rider problem, which we should solve as best we can, there’s a free rider opportunity. And while we whine about the problem, the opportunity has always been far larger and its value grows with every passing day.

The American economist Robert Solow demonstrated in the 1950s that nearly all of the productivity growth in history – particularly our rise from subsistence to affluence since the industrial revolution – was a result not of increasing capital investment, but of people finding better ways of working and playing, and then being copied. A little of this innovation was fostered by intellectual property rights which give temporary monopolies in technology. But much less than you’d think.

Most innovation can’t be patented. And after patents expire in 20 years (it used to be less) it’s open slather. We’re not paying royalties to the estates of Matthew Bolton and James Watt for their refinements to the piston engine. But we’re still free riding on their work. In other words, free-riding made us what we are today.

Get Evonomics in your inbox

So let’s take a step back and address the issue of free-riding from a different perspective. If, as a society today, we had to choose between addressing the free rider problem and seizing the free rider opportunity, taking the latter option wins hands down. In fact we don’t have to choose. We should be doing both as best we can on their merits in individual situations, but it’s a reflection of our mercantilist culture that the “free rider problem” is both a household expression and an endlessly stoked social anxiety whereas the “free rider opportunity” is so unfamiliar that it sounds deeply counterintuitive – subversive even.

The free rider opportunity

At the birth of modernity Thomas Jefferson spoke of the free rider opportunity more eloquently than any statesman then or since:

He who receives an idea from me, receives instruction himself without lessening mine; as he who lights his taper at mine, receives light without darkening me. That ideas should freely spread from one to another over the globe, for the moral and mutual instruction of man, and improvement of his condition, seems to have been peculiarly and benevolently designed by nature, when she made them, like fire, expansible over all space, without lessening their density in any point, and like the air in which we breathe, move, and have our physical being, incapable of confinement or exclusive appropriation.

Far from wanting to ignore the free rider problem, Jefferson was on top of that too, spearheading the institutionalization of intellectual property. But having done so, throughout his life, including in his administration of patents, he sought balance between dealing with the problems and seizing the opportunities presented by free riding. He supported relatively narrow interpretations of patent monopolies around specific applications of technologies to preserve the freedom to copy in divergent fields.

As his words above suggest, Jefferson understood that sharing knowledge spread both prosperity and wisdom from innovators to the whole of humanity and had done so from time immemorial. But there’s also a sense in which he saw the opportunities growing progressively larger and more exciting as we move into the information age. Jefferson was fresh from the rise of blogging – then known as pamphleteering – in which disputants argued back and forth in as close to ‘real-time’ as the printing presses would permit.

Free-riding and public goods

Though rarely (if ever) remarked upon, free riding problems and opportunities lie at the heart of public goods. Theorised initially in 1954 by Paul Samuelson as goods that are “joint in consumption”, the idea is implicit in Vincent and Elinor Ostrom’s quadrant in 1977.

In economic jargon, public goods are both non-excludable and non-rival. For example, Wikipedia currently offers fireworks displays as an example of a public good – at least over a localized area. Everyone can see them – so they are non-excludable. And one person’s enjoyment does not hinder another’s – so they are non-rival.

common

And it turns out that these two characteristics – rivalrousness and excludability – define the dimensions of free riding! If non-excludability creates a potential free rider problem (obstructing a market from charging, and so, providing the good), non-rivalrousness creates a free rider opportunity (once created, Thomas Jefferson’s dream of limitless sharing comes into view.)

And guess which side of this polarity the dismal science orients itself around? As the Ostroms explained in their article: “Public goods . . . present serious problems in human organisation”. This provides some insight as to why our friends from the intellectual property lobby have so much more success appealing to the public’s anxieties about the free rider problem than more moderate voices arguing, as Jefferson did, for strict limits on those rights to minimise the extent to which they obstruct free rider opportunities.

The new public goods of the 21st Century

As I indicated above, we can usually deal with both the free rider problem and opportunities very satisfactorily on their merits. But the new value creation of the 21st Century shows us that sometimes we have to choose. And it shows how to choose if there’s any serious doubt. Imagine you have some service to offer on the web. It’s a service that people will value greatly and as they benefit from it they’ll make their own contributions to the service.

You can solve the free rider problem by supplying the service behind a paywall. So you’ll minimise the extent to which people free ride on your great new service. If people really like it they’ll be prepared to pay good money.

But, but, but but .… a paywall would hit audience numbers hugely, which degrades the extent to which the site can be monetized by advertising and the contributions of the users. So solving the free rider problem hugely degrades the free rider opportunity.

And so it is that a vast portion of the new value that’s been built on the net has come to this fork in the road – and plumped for opportunity. Thus Google generates many hundreds of billions of dollars every year but monetizes only a small fraction of that value. But $60 billion per annum is enough to make its founders rich beyond their wildest dreams.

Ditto Facebook, Twitter and any number of other services. This formula of embracing the free rider opportunity is apparent not just in for profit ventures but in philanthropic ventures such as Wikipedia and the Internet Archive both of which could charge for their services, but only at the cost of massively degrading their mission.

Conclusion

Though the illustrative examples of public goods in economic textbooks are reassuringly worthy – like military defense and public infrastructure – Wikipedia’s more festive image of fireworks radiating out from a city skyscraper better celebrates Jefferson’s dream of sharing human knowledge in its unfolding abundance.

And there’s much more to be said about the future of public goods. But before we can do it we have to go right back the last economist to fully appreciate the indispensable role public goods play at every level of our lives and have done so since our rise from our origins on the African Savannah. And the last economist to do that was the first economist –Scottish moral philosopher Adam Smith.

To be continued .… here

2016 April 26


Donating = Changing Economics. And Changing the World.

Evonomics is free, it’s a labor of love, and it's an expense. We spend hundreds of hours and lots of dollars each month creating, curating, and promoting content that drives the next evolution of economics. If you're like us — if you think there’s a key leverage point here for making the world a better place — please consider donating. We’ll use your donation to deliver even more game-changing content, and to spread the word about that content to influential thinkers far and wide.

MONTHLY DONATION
 $3 / month
 $7 / month
 $10 / month
 $25 / month

ONE-TIME DONATION
You can also become a one-time patron with a single donation in any amount.

If you liked this article, you'll also like these other Evonomics articles...




BE INVOLVED

We welcome you to take part in the next evolution of economics. Sign up now to be kept in the loop!